Català | Castellano | English | Français | Deutsch | Italiano | Galego | Esperanto
En aquest lloc «web» trobareu propostes per fer front a problemes econòmics que esdevenen en tots els estats del món: manca d'informació sobre el mercat, suborns, corrupció, misèria, carències pressupostàries, abús de poder, etc.
Home | Who are we? | Links | Contact and email | Blog

Books and documents:

A short history of money.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà, Brauli Tamarit Tamarit.

Communal Capitalism.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.

An instrument to build peace.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.

Semitic legends concerning the bank.
Agustí Chalaux de Subirà.

Telematic currency and market strategy.
Magdalena Grau, Agustí Chalaux.

The power of money.
Martí Olivella.

Chapter 11. Facing up to things. The power of money. Index. The power of money. Chapter 13. Agility and accuracy. The power of money.

Chapter 12. From clay to silicon, going through gold & paper.

The clay civilizations used clay for a personalized and informative accounting-monetary system (perhaps an element of a wide pacification among townships). The metal civilizations used it to help and improve the exchanges and the warlike, corrupting imperialism. The paper civilization has used clay to control the markets and peoples. The electronics civilization is using it for monetary speculation on a planetary level and to ensure the control of populations.

The clay civilizations (still considered as 'prehistory') probably enjoyed, to certain degree, peace among themselves, oddly enough, as long as they had a personalized and informative monetary system.

Official history starts with the introduction and domination of metals (for currency and weapons): the towns, which had been independent up until then, are submitted to historic imperialisms which have lasted until our days.

Paper introduced a greater degree of refinement in the process of monetary exploitation and in the growth of markets. The bankers took the role of decission-making in economy, peace and war.

The State frontiers have lost their security with electronic money. Any person of any office that «pulls the strings» of money will automatically be playing with the puppets politics, production, consumption, investment...

Every civilization has, among the things which differentiate it from others, some materials, tools, instruments, inventions... which seen from the standpoint of time, we can single out as distinctive of its culture.

For Western civilization, history starts about 4500 years ago when writing first appeared with the Sumer tablets. But even if we adopt this standard as a contituting element of history, we see that along almost 7000 years there were other cultures which already recorded graphic information on clay (chapter 10). These 7000 years of using the same information system in places very distant from each other (and on the whole space in the process of civilization) is a huge puzzle which challenges the 'wonders' of our history.

What else do we know about this long period in which the foundations of agriculture, market, currency, crafts, towns, bank, temples, State... are laid?

In a fertile land, near to large rivers, ethnic communities and inter-ethnic aggregates become settled, their farming improves and they start using some instruments to organize production and trade in its double manifestation, inside each settlement (possibly sharing and with an incipient exchange) and between settlements (with exchange and a growing control on accounting).

This is an important element. The exchange of products is not necessary when property is communal. But this is only possible in communities bound ethnically, by blood, culture and common myths. When this trust is lost and differentiated communal or collective properties appear, becomes necessary exchange among them. These first settlements were made up of small inter-mingled groups -two or three groups uniting to farm, build and protect themselves from the outside. This protection most probably caused the building of walls, which progressively became impregnable ramparts when the settlements became wealthy, and multi-ethnic towns, with less trust inside and more dangers outside. The walls became a very effective defence tool. It is possible that the tons enjoyed peace amongst themselves during a period of some thousand years, due to the effectivity of these walls. Each one independent, jealous of its autonomy and sure of its defence, during the day it opened its gates to merchants arriving with caravans and to strangers from other towns. In the market place trade transactions were made, which were recorded in the temple book-keeping. At night, outsiders had to leave the town. It seems that the introduction of an informative system such as tokens could not have been feasible without some sort of 'peacemaking' rules (result of defensive, non-offensive, mechanisms) which, during thousands of years reached a stability and acceptance and, at the same time, reinforced security and economic defence.

To carry on the hypothetic tale we must make a very important distinction, even if the words 'empire' and 'imperialism' are commonly used as synonims. We shall call these towns 'empire-towns', meaning that their inner agreement of the constitution was freely made by the groups and inter-groups adopting it. The empire-town looked for a common outer defence ('imparare') which allowed free game and the help among groups within it.

Official history starts with the Sumerian writing, but it also starts with a completely different situation from what we have described up until now. This situation can be defined, by contrast, as 'imperialism': one of the towns manages to overcome the others and to keep them, by right of conquest, under its control. If we call historic imperialisms 'empires', the confusion, besides being terrible, is suspiciously maintained by the imperialisms. These, supported by official history, want to deny the historic legitimity of any free agreement of mutual help among groups. Imperialists want to underline that «towns» are unfeasible, that only unification' gives power, and that this must be done by the imposition of one of the groups, towns or States..., as history shows abundantly.

However, history starts not only when writing appears but also with a 'new' reality: imperialism. And with it, expansion, annexation and wars of domination. Unaccountably, the oldest Semites we know, the Akkadians, who had been lately penetrating into the culture and the lands of the Sumerians, upset the stable empire-towns. Sargon the Great, of Akkad, establishes the first imperialism of history, he destroys the old order and introduces the birth of the 'history of the imperialisms', the only one which has been considered this up until now. The history of empire-towns, free and independent, is prehistory! There is almost nothing in common. That was a different history in which historians of imperialisms are not even interested in mentioning. The garden of Eden is completely lost. It is a myth for children. Historic and civilized man 'is' what we know, and he has always been like that.

The Great Sargon's biography is very illustrative (and, as we shall see, original!) as he was «of humble birth and was abandoned by his mother in the Euphrates». Saved by the courtiers of the Sumerian king, he became his cupbearer. Later «he revolted against him, assumed power and built a new capital, Akkad. A clear example of a warrior king, conqueror and founder of empires (imperialisms!) bent on unifying Mesopotamia». He conquered and submitted most of the towns from «the Persian Gulf in the south to the region later occupied by Assyria in the north. In the south-east he reached Elam [...], he penetrated the north of Syria and perhaps also Asia Minor1». A perfect description of the appearance of imperialism and of official history.

There remains an important question fron these facts: how is it that this Akkadian king managed to subdue the other towns which had been independent during 7000 years? The walls enclosing them could not be destroyed by military means until much later, when Alexander the Great (another 'Great' emperor) used the catapult and the mechanic ballista in the sieges of Tyre and Sidon, 300 years before Christ. But we are talking about the Sumerian towns being subdued 2000 years before any war device was able to knock down fortresses!

The Sumerians, who were peaceful inhabitants of those lands during centuries, and who had been great cultural creators and inventors of the systems of tokens and bullae, therefore, of writing, were invaded and subdued by the Semites-Akkadians, who gained control of Mesopotamia in a few years. The title «king of Sumer and Akkad» was held by the following dynasties during over one thousand years with the evident intention of staying in power, based on the legitimacy of the first (cultivated) inhabitants and of the (barbaric) conquerors.

«On the other hand, there is a meaningful analogy between Sumer and Greece, for they not only were two important cultural centres, which gave shape to other civilizations, but, their basic political nucleus was the state-town2». In the same way that Greece became a victim of Roman imperialism, Sumer was defeated by the Akkadian imperialism. It now appears certain that 2700 years before Christ things began to change in Sumer, with wars among the towns. In three hundred years the Akkadians won and 'unified' them. In the same period and in the same areas, the bullae system started to be substituted for writing, at the same time the Semites started to master the secrets of precious metals -gold, silver, bronze-; of weight, with the precision scales; and quality, with aqua regia and the touchstone.

There is nothing that indicates how this triumphant warrior managed to get into the walled cities. We must remember that perhaps it was no coincidence, as Sargon had been a cupbearer -in charge of cellars, measures and treasures. It is a daring hypothesis, and in any case a challenging one. A impregnable militarily town has only one weak spot: its gates. If the complicity -treason- of some town official is obtained, invaders can get in by night and seize it. But how could complicity be obtained? What was so valuable, that would cause an officer to take the risk of betraying his own town? Any valuable present would have aroused suspicion: how could he have obtained valuable goods without any operation being recorded in the temple, nor any operation made in the market place? To accept the position of 'town governor', appointed by the conquering king, was an unforgivable offence which would cause a very dangerous nurderous hate. Eagerness for power had always been very limited by circumstances.

Sargon's ingenuity was to discover that there was a solution: to give a lot of gold in exchange for the 'complicity' of opening the gates. And at the same time, to promise that the 'normal' trend of the last years, when the Semites accepted gold as a 'currency' for all the exchanges, would become general with the new king. He would abolish the system of bullae and records; you could buy and sell without the Sumerians' administrative and 'oldfashioned' obstacles. It was certainly a good deal. Even so, if this officer did not accept, they would kill him and give the position to another officer...

The myths of 'miraculous' seizings of fortified towns are probably meaningful. Tokens have been found in the ruins of Jericho. And one day Jericho, the impregnable, was assaulted by Semites due to the fact that its walls were miraculously pulled down without fighting. They only paraded a gold ark in front of it... At that time, as much as now, it was necessary to keep up appearances, and conquerors did not like to show their tricks. They prefered to hide their shame under magnificent and mysterious myths which gave them heavenly support. The Trojan horse may be one more myth concealing the power of gold.

Under the Akkadian domination the role of the temples was reinforced and they were unified with the State; bureaucracy, compulsory taxes, oppression of women, ritual murders, monumental buildings, unceasing wars and conspirations increasesd. Since then, all the 'civilizations' have shared the same historic features. All has been sold and purchased with total impunity.

Since then, documental invoicing for book-keeping purposes has been separated from payment with the monetary instrument. Since then, bankers, tradesmen, and State have had their accounting systems, which have allowed to grant credits and collect interests; to create inflations and deflations, while increasing, reducing or forging 'currency' (always limited and limitable) according to their own intersts. Since then, book-keeping has always been false, without an exact, parallel counterpart in actual exchanges.

The paper -and printing- civilization has developed the same issue: to improve the accounting and credit systems for a few and to 'free' them from the drawbacks of metals by the emission of banknotes (always controlled, too, by those who emit them arbitrarily, by definition). Cheques and money orders have still added more manoevring capacity.

The most invisible subtlety, but also the most powerful, has been reached. With the birth of the silicon civilization, and the basic material of chips, that is of electronics and telematics (data processing handled at a distance). It is neither gold nor paper but electronic recordings. But their structure is still, in its basic traits, the same as 4500 years ago, and to the same ends: not to leave any track, to control information, and to monopolize the ability to create purchasing power.

The hypothesis given out on the origin of 'official history' must evidently be submitted to a much more serious study. Presenting it has, however, a twofold function: induce further work and, open a challenging path on the subject under consideration. «Se non è vero, è ben trovato».


Notes:

1Raimón Griñó, «Gran Enciclopèdia Catalana», Barcelona, 1979, vol. 13, p. 349.
2Ib., vol. 14, p. 67.

Chapter 11. Facing up to things. The power of money. Index. The power of money. Chapter 13. Agility and accuracy. The power of money.

Home | Who we are? | Links | Contact and email